Why Nations Fail - Book Review
Why Nations Fail by Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson
The main thesis of this book makes sense. “Extractive economies” run by an elite (such as aristocracies and slave economies) do not lead to sustained growth: people have little incentive to invest in new enterprises because the elite may take their property, and the elite often deliberately blocks growth because it could unsettle their privileges. “Inclusive Economies,” with pluralistic governments, secure property rights and rule of law, lead to sustained economic growth.
The main thesis of this book makes sense. “Extractive economies” run by an elite (such as aristocracies and slave economies) do not lead to sustained growth: people have little incentive to invest in new enterprises because the elite may take their property, and the elite often deliberately blocks growth because it could unsettle their privileges. “Inclusive Economies,” with pluralistic governments, secure property rights and rule of law, lead to sustained economic growth.
There is a “which came first” problem, because there must be
some degree of economic growth before pluralistic institutions develop. Thus,
there were factories in England in the early seventeenth century, and the economic
changes that had already occurred by this time made the middle class powerful
enough that it could ultimately develop a pluralistic government with rule of
law after the Glorious Revolution. Nevertheless, it does make sense that this
“inclusive” government accelerated economic growth and made it sustainable, by
providing the legal framework needed to encourage investment.
Yet this book claims that extractive or inclusive
institutions are essentially the only thing that determines whether there can
be sustained growth, and its wide-ranging history skips details about several
countries that might challenge this thesis.
Switzerland threw off the aristocracy and developed an
inclusive government long before England did, so why didn’t it develop the
industrial revolution before England?
Obviously, because it is a land-locked, mountainous country, which
lacked the transportation that could integrate it with the world economy. Thus, it seems that geography is also
important.
In the United States, this book uses the examples of Virginia,
the Carolinas, and Maryland to explain why we developed an inclusive
economy. It says that these states were
founded by aristocrats who wanted to create an extractive economy but who did
not have enough indigenous people to exploit (as Mexico did), so they were
forced to develop the more inclusive institutions that make the United States
more prosperous than Mexico. Yet we all
know that these southern states developed an extractive economy based on
slavery and that they were economic backwaters that were late to industrialize,
while our industrial revolution began in the north. A later chapter talks about
the industrial revolution beginning in the north because of the extractive
economy based on slavery in the south, but without revising the earlier claim
that America’s inclusive institutions began in these southern colonies. It
seems that the southern states were founded by aristocrats, who managed to
create an extractive economy despite the lack of indigenous people to exploit,
while the northern states were founded by commercial interests (like New York)
or by people seeking to be self-sufficient for religious reasons (like
Massachusetts), who were more willing to create an inclusive economy. Thus, it seems culture is also important.
Imperial Germany is the most puzzling case. Before World War I, it had an authoritarian
government, and yet it was the fast growing economy in Europe, challenging
England for economic dominance. At the
time, leftist economists used imperial Germany as evidence that an
authoritarian governments were the best engines of economic growth. South Korea and Taiwan have a similar
history: development was successful under authoritarian governments, and these
countries did not have inclusive governments until after growth had gone a
long way.
Switzerland and the United States suggest that the contrast
between inclusive and extractive institutions is an important part of the
explanation of why nations become prosperous or poor, but that we have to
modify this explanation so that it also includes other factors, such as
geography and culture.
Imperial Germany, South Korea, and Taiwan suggest that the
contrast between inclusive and extractive institutions might not always be the
key to development after all. These countries challenge some of this books
predictions, such as its claim that China’s growth will not be sustained.
It is possible that there is some explanation for growth in
imperial Germany, South Korea, and Taiwan that can save the thesis of this
book, but the book simply skips over these countries without explaining
them.
It has a map of countries that had abolished serfdom by 1800
(map 8), and it claims that this predicts their later economic success; yet the
map shows that Greece had abolished serfdom while Germany had not, and we all
know which of these two countries is more successful today. It mentions that
Napoleon brought inclusive economic institutions to the western part of
Germany, but it doesn’t explain why the united Germany was led by Prussia, its
easternmost and most authoritarian state.
The failure to explain Germany, South Korea, and Taiwan is
this book’s greatest weakness as history.
The failure to question the value of economic growth is its
greatest weakness as politics.
Clearly, growth was beneficial at first, when it was needed
to reduce poverty. Clearly, countries
that have had growth, like the United States, are better off than countries
that have never had growth, such as sub-Sahara Africa. But after a country has a comfortable standard
of living, further growth provides diminishing benefits and produces real
environmental costs that we will have to deal with in the coming centuries.
This book takes the essentially conservative position that
we should continue policies that were useful in the past because they promoted
rapid economic growth. But policies that were useful in the past will not
necessarily be useful in the future.
When people ask why nations fail a century from now,
“extractive” governments and economies may be less important answer than global
warming.